]]]]]]]]]] THE EFFECT OF FUEL ECONOMY STANDARDS [[[[[[[[[ ON AUTOMOBILE SAFETY (2/2/1990) [Abridgement of Robert W. Crandall and John D. Graham, ``The Effect of Fuel Economy Standards on Automobile Safety'', Journal of Law and Economics 32(1):97-118 (April 1989). Published by The University of Chicago.] [Kindly uploaded by Freeman 10602PANC] Introduction In 1975, Congress passed the Energy Policy Conservation Act (EPCA), which established mandatory fuel economy standards for all new automobiles sold in the United States beginning with the 1978 model year. These standards, called the Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) Standards, were then designed to increase the incentive for automobile producers to improve fuel efficiency beyond that dictated by market forces, which were being distorted by government controls on crude oil and refined products. By the 1985 model year, all automobile producers were to have achieved at least a 27.5 miles-per-gallon (MPG) rating for their automobiles. There has been a lively debate about the effectiveness of the CAFE program as a conservation measure and about its effect on the domestic automobile industry, particularly in light of the sharp decline in real gasoline prices since 1981. However, we know of no quantitative investigations of the effects of this policy on other social goals, such as motor vehicle safety. In this article, we estimate the effects of the CAFE program on the average weight of new automobiles, the mix of large and small vehicles sold in the United States, and the ultimate effects of this new fleet size on vehicle safety. In doing so, we link economic models of the auto industry with a rich literature on the effects of vehicle weight on the susceptibility of occupants to injury and death. Our new empirical results suggest that CAFE will be responsible for several thousand additional fatalities over the life of each model-year's cars. We conclude that the real social cost of government-mandated fuel economy is much greater than is commonly believed. The CAFE Program Under the CAFE program, all automobile producers with sales in the U.S. market must meet a minimum average fuel-efficiency standard, defined as a harmonically weighted average of the city and highway EPA mileage ratings, for all their cars. Companies that produce in the United States and import from other countries must satisfy this standard separately for their imported and domestic models. The fuel-efficiency standard was set in legislation at 18 MPG for the 1978 model year, rising to 27.5 MPG by the 1985 model year. The Department of Transportation (DOT) was responsible for setting the precise level of the standard for the 1981-84 model years and for 1986 and beyond. In addition, DOT may adjust the standards for changing conditions (such as changes in technological or economic feasibility). Failure to meet the standard results in civil penalties of $50 per MPG per car produced. Were General Motors to fail to meet the 1987 or 1988 standard by just 1.0 MPG, for example, the company could be subject to penalties of $200 million per year or more. The sharp rise in gasoline prices after the Iranian revolution provided automobile producers with sufficient market incentives to meet and even exceed the CAFE standards through 1981. All three major U.S. producers exceeded the standards by a wide margin (Table 1 [omitted]), building up credits that they could carry over for three years to cover any future shortfalls. As gasoline prices began to fall after 1981, the CAFE standards began to bind. By 1983 Ford and General Motors began falling short of the standard. At first they could use credits accumulated prior to 1983, when they exceeded the CAFE standard, to offset these shortfalls. By 1985, however, it was apparent that their shortfall for 1986 would be very large, inducing them to petition the Department of Transportation for a relaxation of the standard to 26 MPG, which was granted. In a subsequent revision, the 26 MPG standard was extended to the 1987-88 model years. With real gasoline prices in 1988 as low as in the pre-OPEC era, pressure has been mounting for a revocation of the CAFE program altogether. Although the Reagan administration appeared to support revocation, resistance in Congress was substantial. Because CAFE is a program of trade restriction, some Congressmen from automobile-producing areas may be loathe to eliminate it. Since CAFE forces U.S. manufacturers to meet a fuel-efficiency standards for their domestic production alone, CAFE discourages them from importing low-cost small cars from Asia or Eastern Europe even though such a strategy may provide automobiles at the lowest cost to U.S. consumers. To meet CAFE while producing larger cars, they must produce small cars in the United States. CAFE is more of a burden to Ford and General Motors than to Chrysler, since Chrysler has moved away from the production of large cars. This has lead Chrysler to support the CAFE program aggressively while Ford and General Motors (GM) seek relief from it. Further support comes from those who fear a sharp rise in gasoline prices in the next decade and thus see CAFE as a prudent conservation policy. Unfortunately, little attention has been focused on another aspect of the CAFE program. Fuel efficiency is most easily improved by reducing vehicle weight, but lower-weight vehicles tend to provide less crash protection to vehicle occupants than larger, heavier cars. In theory it may be possible to build lighter cars without compromising safety, but analysts have shown that the ``downsized'' vehicles of the late 1970s and early 1980s are less safe in crashes than the heavier cars they replaced. As a result, by inducing U.S. producers to offer lighter cars, the CAFE program may be increasing the number of deaths and injuries on U.S. highways compared to the number that would occur without CAFE. This is a real social cost of pursuing fuel efficiency that policymakers have been reluctant to acknowledge. Indeed, the federal agency that administers the CAFE program, the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (NHTSA), has done little to inform legislators and the public about the potentially adverse safety effects of CAFE. The Effects of CAFE on Vehicle Weight Since planning, designing, engineering, and tooling a new model require at least four years, automobile manufacturers must begin to plan to meet future CAFE standards based upon extremely uncertain forecasts of the level of gasoline prices in the years in which a model is actually sold. Moreover, they cannot know in advance how well any line of vehicles will survive in the marketplace. Thus, it is very likely that the average level of fuel efficiency realized in an automobile producer's full line of automobiles in any given year at its expected selling prices will deviate substantially from its plan. If the deviation is positive, the manufacturer may simply accumulate CAFE credits for future use in the event of shortfalls -- such as those GM and Ford have encountered since 1983. But if the deviation is negative at planned prices, the manufacturer may elect to raise large-car prices or large-engine option prices and lower the prices of smaller, less powerful (and, therefore, more fuel-efficient) cars. In short, it is the manufacturer's expectations of fuel prices and CAFE approximately four years in advance of the vehicle's production that is likely to influence the engine and vehicle-weight choices for individual models. Once these choices are locked in, the manufacturer can only use prices (or nonprice rationing) to meet CAFE if he finds that his planning has left him short of the standard, or he can petition for a reduction in the CAFE standard. Much of the practical effect of CAFE in vehicle design has been upon the weight of automobiles. The design of transmissions, the choice of ignition and fuel-injection systems, tires, and engine oils have all been affected by CAFE, but empirical analysis of the effect of all of these ``technical design'' factors on CAFE suggests that they are only slightly more important than weight reduction. Through materials substitutions, improved design, and reduction of interior volume, manufacturers have greatly reduced vehicle weight and increased fuel efficiency. As Table 2 [omitted] demonstrates, the average U.S. automobile has undergone a 23 percent reduction in weight since 1974. With this reduction in weight, an even greater proportional reduction in engine size has occurred. The combined effect of these two reductions on fuel economy has been to raise MPG by about 24 percent. [Remainder of page 101 omitted; pp 102-109 omitted; part of p. 110 omitted. The omitted pages explain the author's model and the ways they estimated the values of the various parameters.] The Effect of Vehicle Weight on Safety In research performed over the past fifteen years, traffic safety analysts have found that occupants of lighter cars incur an elevated risk of serious injury and death in crashes compared to occupants of heavier cars. This statistical association has been demonstrated for both single-vehicle and multivehicle crashes. ``Weight'' is chosen as the independent variable in these investigations because it is both easily measured and strongly correlated with other vehicle attributes such as wheel-base, track, ``size'' in general, hood length, trunk size, and engine displacement. Although the precise physical mechanisms by which weight (or its correlates) affect safety are not fully understood, the negative relationship between weight and occupant fatality risk is one of the most secure findings in the safety literature. The most sophisticated research on the weight-safety relationship has been performed by Leonard Evans at General Motor's Research Laboratories. Based on a statistical model of car mass and real-world fatal crashes that holds driver behavior constant, Evans reports an empirical relationship of the form L(m) = a * exp(-0.00106 * m), (4) where L(m) is the relative likelihood of fatality in a car of mass m (in kilograms). Using this equation, we calculated that the 500-pound reduction in the average weight of 1989 cars that is attributable to CAFE is associated with roughly a 27 percent increase in occupant fatality risk. This estimate should be regarded as an upper bound on the adverse safety effects of CAFE because it assumes that drivers of lighter cars do not realize the additional dangers and take precautionary responses. Some evidence reported by the Opinion Research Corporation and Winston et al. suggests, for example, that occupants of lighter cars are more likely to wear safety belts than occupants of heavier cars. To account for the possibility of behavioral response, Evans reported results of an alternate statistical model that predicts the net effect of both vehicle size and behavioral responses on fatality risk. His estimated equation is of the form L(m) = a * exp(-0.00058 * m). (5) Using this equation, we calculated that CAFE is responsible for a 14 percent increase in occupant fatality risk in 1989 cars. In other words, drivers (and passengers) appear to offset about half of the physical disadvantages of lighter cars through various types of behavioral responses (for example, enhanced maneuverability and increased use of seat belts). Our rough estimate is therefore that the 500-pound or 14 percent reduction in the average weight of 1989 cars caused by CAFE is associated with a 14-27 percent increase in occupant fatality risk. This range does not account for a variety of second-order effects of CAFE on safety. First, if CAFE curtails overall car sales (as some evidence suggests is the case), that means that the older and predominantly heavier cars will stay on the road longer. Although that outcome might seem good for safety, one must also consider that the oldest cars in the fleet are not equipped with a variety of safety features (some mandated by NHTSA) that were initiated in the 1965-1975 period. Several studies have found that these safety features were quite effective. We assume that these two effects cancel each other. Second, our rough estimates are based on models of the weight-safety relationship for single-vehicle crashes -- which NHTSA reports account for about one-half of occupant fatalities. We have not performed separate calculations of the effects of lighter cars on fatalities in multivehicle crashes. Since the ``weight effect'' estimated by Evans is somewhat larger for multivehicle crashes, this omission will cause us to underestimate the overall adverse safety effects of CAFE. We are aware of only one line of reasoning that has been advanced that might undermine our result that CAFE is responsible for a substantial increase in occupant fatality risk. In their regulatory analysis of CAFE, NHTSA reports that the number of passenger car occupant deaths in the United States has been declining since 1980, even though the average weight of cars on the road has been declining. They infer that the CAFE program must not be a significant detriment to safety. We question this line of reasoning. First, NHTSA analysts have shown that the number of passenger car occupant fatalities declined during this period because of the 1980 and 1982 recessions and the national campaign against drunk driving. Second, the mere retirement of older, less safe cars should have reduced the fatality rate substantially. We submit that the decline in car occupant fatalities from 1980 to 1985 might have been more dramatic had CAFE not been in effect. Finally, the NHTSA analysis fails to address the fact that other variables -- such as rising real incomes -- tend to depress fatality rates over time. The motor vehicle fatality rate has been declining for decades for just this reason. [remainder of p. 112 omitted.] [pp. 113-114 omitted. Part of pp. 115 omitted. The omitted pages describe certain checks on the model.] Quantifying the Omitted Social Cost of CAFE To provide a national estimate of the safety-related costs of CAFE, we forecasted the fatality toll for just one year's production over an expected ten-year life of these cars. This provides a clean analysis that ignores the effect of CAFE on the mix of older cars on the road. If CAFE induces manufacturers to offer smaller cards and greater fuel economy than an unregulated industry would offer, it will undoubtedly lead to some postponement of the replacement of older, larger cars. These older cars are less safe than newer models of the same weight but may be more crashworthy than the prospectively smaller 1989 cars. We simply ignore these second-order transitional effects of CAFE. In calendar year 1985 there were about 25,000 car occupant fatalities in a fleet of 130 million vehicles, which translates into 1.9 fatalities per 10,000 cars. If we assume that a model year of car sales averages about 11.2 million, and if these cars experience this fatality rate through their ten-year life, and if 4 percent of the remaining 1989 models are scrapped each year, there will be a total of 17,800 fatalities in these cars. Without CAFE we estimate that the fatality toll would be much smaller, 13,900-15,600. In sum, CAFE is estimated to be responsible for 2,200-3,900 excess occupant fatalities over ten years of a given model years' use. It is plausible to believe that the inverse relationship between car weight and safety also holds for serious nonfatal injuries. NHTSA (1985) estimates that the frequency of ``serious nonfatal injuries'' among car occupants is about five times larger that the frequency of fatalities. Hence we estimate that CAFE will also be responsible for an additional 11,000-19,500 serious nonfatal injuries to occupants of the prospective 1989 model cars. A ``serious'' injury is defined as a score of 3 or greater on the American Association of Automotive Medicine's (six-point) Abbreviated Injury Scale. Typical ``serious'' cases include compound fractures and internal organ injuries. These adverse safety outcomes can be converted to dollars by using market estimates of the value of safety. At a conservative value of $1 million per statistical life and $20,000 per statistical injury, the adverse safety effects of CAFE translate into a social cost of $2.4 to $4.3 billion over the life of 1989 cars. Assuming a real discount rate of 5 percent, the present value of CAFE's safety costs equals $1.9 to $3.4 billion for the assumed ten-year life of 1989 model-year automobiles. A Cost-Benefit Calculation We have estimated that abolition of the CAFE program (with sufficient lead time) would have led to a 500-pound increase in the average weight of a 1989 model-year automobile and a reduction of 2,200-3,900 fatalities over a ten-year life of these cars. These lighter cars would, however, consume less fuel over this ten-year period, thereby offsetting some of the welfare loss of the higher vehicle fatality rate. A 500-pound increase in average vehicle weight represents a 16.1 percent increase in weight of 1989 model year cars. Crandall et al. found that the elasticity of MPG with respect to weight is between 0.7 and 0.8; therefore, MPG would have been 11.3 to 12.9 percent lower and the cost per mile would have been 12.7 to 14.8 percent higher without CAFE for 1989 automobiles. Most estimates of the long-run elasticity of demand for vehicle-miles traveled are clustered around -0.50. As a result, we may conclude that total travel in 1989 automobiles would have been about 6.4-7.4 percent less without CAFE, all other things being equal. The effect on annual gasoline consumption would be equal to 1.076-1.087 times the consumption with CAFE in place. In short, CAFE saved 5.5-6.3 percent of gasoline consumed by 1989 models. Assuming a 5 percent real social discount rate, an annual consumption of 500 gallons per 1989 model per year with CAFE, and a price of gasoline equal to $1 per gallon in 1989, the present value of the gasoline saved by CAFE over ten years (assuming constant real gasoline prices) would be $2.4-$2.8 billion for all 11.2 million cars sold or $1.8-$2.2 billion for all 1989 automobiles except the Japanese imports that are presently not affected by CAFE. In short, the savings of gasoline are not significantly larger than our estimate of the lost value due to increased highway injuries and fatalities. Further Considerations It is not our purpose to provide a full cost-benefit analysis of the CAFE program, but we cannot leave the reader with the impression that the appropriate measure of the social value of CAFE is the difference between fuel saved and the added costs of reduced highway safety. Obviously, the CAFE program forced vehicle manufacturers to invest more resources in developing fuel efficiency than 1985 gasoline prices warranted. Indeed, we have shown that it was CAFE, not the price of gasoline that drove average MPG in the 1978-1985 period. The excessive investment in fuel efficiency added substantially to the social cost of CAFE. In Crandall et al., the elasticity of vehicle cost with respect to MPG was estimated to be approximately 0.35. In a 1977 analysis of the prospective compliance costs of CAFE, the Department of Transportation estimated that raising average fuel economy from 20.5 to 27.6 would cost between $362 and $407 (1977 dollars) per car, or about 6.0-6.6 percent of the average price of a car in 1977. This suggests a cost elasticity with respect to MPG of between 0.16 and 0.18. Even using this lower ex ante estimate, the excess compliance costs of CAFE may be estimated to be 0.6-0.7 [percent] of the cost of a passenger car for each additional MPG. At a price of $15,000 per car, the cost of each MPG for a given model year's cars is $1 billion. In short, the search for technologies to meet CAFE can be very expensive and easily swamp the fuel savings generated by CAFE. The CAFE program also resultults in a mix of cars that is less desirable than that which would be produced for 1985 gasoline prices, thereby reducing the number of vehicles sold. This, in turn, translates into a deadweight loss since society foregoes the additional output that is valued above the incremental costs of production. And this reduction in new vehicles creates another social cost -- the extension of the useful life of older cars that are less safe and create more pollution than newer models. In short, the full costs of the CAFE program are likely to be considerable even if one excludes the direct safety effect. Conclusion Earlier analyses of the effects of fuel-economy regulation have missed an important point. Fuel economy regulation inevitably leads to smaller, lighter cars that are inherently less safe than the cars that would be produced without a binding fuel economy constraint. We have shown that even if the pursuit of fuel economy were costless to producers the cost of the added loss of life and serious injury from traffic fatalities would more than offset its benefits in reduction of gasoline consumption for 1989 model year cars. We estimate that these 1989 model year cars will be responsible for 2,200-3,900 additional fatalities over the next ten years because of CAFE. Thus, when any discussion of energy conservation focuses on the externalities in energy consumption, we would suggest that all such externalities be included. When safety considerations are included, CAFE appears to be a very costly social policy. * * *
Return to the ground floor of this tower
Return to the Main Courtyard
Return to Fort Freedom's home page